BUDGET LINES: As shown in Chapter 2, consumers are constrained in what they are able to buy due to their limited income and the prices of goods they wish to buy. Th ese two important underpinning principles of consumer behaviour are brought together in the idea of a budget line. Th is shows numerically all the possible combinations of two products that a consumer can purchase with a given income and fi xed prices.
Suppose someone has $200 to spend on two products, A and B. Assume the price of A is $20 and the price of B is $10. Table 7.2 shows the possible combinations that can be purchased. Each of the combinations would cost $200 in total. Figure 7.1a shows the budget line for this situation. Any point along this line will produce an outcome where consumption is maximised for this level of income.
If there is a change in the price of one good, with income remaining unchanged, then the budget line will pivot. For example, if the price of product B falls, then more of this product can be purchased at all levels of income. Th e budget line will shift outwards, from its pivot at point A. Th is is shown in Figure 7.1b. So, if the price of B falls by a third, then 30 of good B can now be purchased with an income of $200.
As the price of B has fallen relative to that of A, which is unchanged, consumers will substitute B for A. This is known as the substitution effect of a price change. It is always the case that the rational consumer will substitute towards the product which has become relatively cheaper. With the fall in the price of B, the consumer actually has more money to spend on other products, B included. Real income has therefore increased, which may mean that a consumer may now actually purchase more of product B. Th is is called the income effect of a price change.
INDIFFERENCE CURVES
Th e budget constraint referred to above showed what
combination of goods a consumer could buy with given
income and the prices of goods. Th is is only part of the reason why consumers buy particular goods – what is also
relevant is consumer preference. Consumers will only buy
a particular good if it is something that they actually want
or prefer when having to choose between alternatives.
Consumer preferences can be represented diagrammatically
by what are known as indiff erence curves.
Indiff erence curve: this shows the diff erent combinations
of two goods that give a consumer equal satisfaction.
KEY TERM
As the name suggests, an indiff erence curve shows
the diff erent combinations of two goods that give the
consumer equal satisfaction. Figure 7.2 shows two such
indiff erence curves out of the many that can apply to a
particular consumer. Considering indiff erence curve I1,
the consumer is indiff erent with respect to combinations
X, Y or Z since each are on the same indiff erence curve.
If the consumer moves from point Z to Y, then the
consumption of good B falls at the expense of an increase
in consumption of good A. Point Y though still represents
a situation where the consumer is still equally happy with
the combination of goods that are being consumed.
Th e slope of the indiff erence curve is important – it
represents the extent to which the consumer is willing to
substitute one good for another. Looking at Figure 7.2,
both the curves slope more steeply from left to right
showing that when consuming large amounts of good A,
the consumer is willing to give up rather more of this good
when consumption of good B is small. Th e rate at which
the consumer is willing to substitute one good for another
in this way is known as the marginal rate of substitution.
Th e budget line constraint and the indiff erence curve
can now be used together to show the eff ect of a change
in income on the consumption of two goods. Th is is
indicated in Figure 7.3. A consumer’s choice is optimal at
the point where the budget line touches or is at a tangent
to the highest indiff erence curve. So, E1 will give the
consumer the maximum combined consumption of goods
A and B given the budget constraint shown by the budget
line B1.
If income increases then this will allow the consumer
to choose a better combination of goods A and B. Th is will
usually be more of each good. So, if the budget constraint
rises to B2, then the consumer will increase consumption
of good A and also of good B, albeit to a lesser extent.
E2 is the new optimal position, where more of both goods are being consumed. Th e change in position from E1 to E2
is what occurs when both goods are normal goods. If the
increase in income or budget constraint results in less of
one good being consumed then this is an inferior good.
When there is a fall in consumer income, the budget
line shift s to the left in a parallel way. Th is indicates
that both goods are normal and that less of each will be
consumed.
Income and substitution eff ects of a price change using indiff erence curves
Th e income and substitution eff ects of a price change were
briefl y outlined earlier. Th ese eff ects can now be interpreted
using indiff erence curves. Th is is shown in Figure 7.4.
If the price of good A falls, then this means that the
consumer has more spending power. Th is is represented
by the new budget constraint B2. Th e price of good B
remains the same which is why B2 pivots upwards to a
new position. Th e extent of change that occurs consists of
two stages. Th ese are:
1 A movement along the initial indiff erence curve I1 to point
E2. This is the substitution eff ect. It is so-called since the
consumer buys less of good B as it is now relatively more
expensive than good A.
2 A shift upwards to a higher indiff erence curve, moving from
point E2 to E3. This is the income eff ect. As the consumer
has more spending power, it is positive in the case of both
goods, resulting in an increase in consumption of good B as
well as good A.
In the case of good A, the income and substitution eff ects
are both positive, resulting in a substantial increase
in consumption. For good B, the substitution eff ect is
negative but the fall in consumption is to some extent
off set by the positive income eff ect. So here, the income and substitution eff ects are pulling in opposite directions.
In Figure 7.4 there is a fall in consumption of good B as the
substitution eff ect is stronger than the income eff ect.
In the case of inferior goods, as we saw in Chapter 2,
when incomes rise above a certain point consumers tend to
substitute more expensive and better quality alternatives.
Here, the income eff ect is negative. Whether this leads to
a fall in consumption will depend on the relative strength
of the substitution eff ect. If this is greater than the income
eff ect, then more of the inferior good will be consumed.
Budget lines and indiff erence curves assume we are
dealing with rational consumers; the reality is that this is
not necessarily true for many consumers.